What “being wrong” means in the world of macroeconomic forecasting.

Authors Publication date
2015
Publication type
Proceedings Article
Summary Economic forecasting aims at outlining possible futures and thus forming actors’ expectations. It describes an institutional environment actors conform to. Expectations look similar to what Keynes (1936) named “convention” and may give rise to speculative bubbles and self-fulfilling prophecies (Orléan, 2011). The latter provides paradoxical evidence of the institutional nature of foreseen environment: the common belief that behaviors shall take future states of the economy into consideration contributes to the actual coming of these states. To put it in the classical economic terms of F. H. Knight, (1921), economic forecasting is a way to shift from uncertain to risky futures by translating scenarios about the future into numbers, e.g. GDP growth forecasts. Forecasts may be regarded as “beliefs” which guide economic actions. They emerge and endure because the reasons for which they are endorsed make sense to actors located in a peculiar historic environment (Weber, 1905). A key issue is thus that of beliefs-standing in adverse situations and of the conditions under which rational actors interpret a sign as a “confirmation” or an “invalidation” of their beliefs. One of the key issues of the presentation is to understand how beliefs and expectations maintain when challenged, or proven “wrong” – and therefore to deal with the issue of “error” in the field of economic forecasting. The word “error” (as well as adjectives like “right” or “wrong”) is kept between quotes to underline it is not here considered from a positivist point of view which attempts to assess forecasts accuracies to a so-called “reality”, but regarded with respect to how actors react to what they regard as “erroneous” statements. In other words, the presentation studies the conditions under which beliefs are “suspended” in situations of fictional expectations (Beckert, 2013). It argues “error” can be defined in various ways, depending on the way forecasting is regarded: the technical limit of a practical activity, a drawback with the founding beliefs of a field, or a threat to forecasters’ trustworthiness and market positions. Firstly, “error” is to be understood with reference to the practical activity of macroeconomic forecasting. Economic future is not known and the coming economic situation is too singular and complex to be exhaustively described, hence forecasting involves conjectures and deliberation: it implies “prudential practices” (Champy, 2011). This process decisively relies on the gathering of information through different channels, including both fellow forecasters and economic actors (Evans, 1997. Reichman, 2013). The forecasting “work in progress” leads to continuous revision in order to reduce “residual errors”. In such perspective, “error” marks the ever-postponed limit to knowledge and highlights the discrepancies between what is known (of the relationship between variables in an econometric model and the values they are expected to take) and the actual economic situations. Secondly, ex post-assessed “errors” are not usually considered as “mistakes” (from a forecaster) but as results of events that could not have been anticipated: the more forecasters missed them, the more unexpectable they were. Drawing from the example of the Survey of Professional Forecasters conducted by the ECB, the presentation shed light on the ways “errors” are explained by forecasters, who emphasize unforeseen inflationist shocks or the similarities of information used by forecasters (Garcia, 2003.
Topics of the publication
Themes detected by scanR from retrieved publications. For more information, see https://scanr.enseignementsup-recherche.gouv.fr